International Macroeconomics

 

Consider a small open economy that lives for two periods, only, (t and t + 1; for
all purposes to some extent if it makes it easier you can think of this as t =
0 and t = 1) and is inhabited by a continuum of identical individuals grouped into an
aggregate risk-sharing household. Each period aggregate output Yt
is produced via the
function Yt = ZtLt where Zt
is exogenous productivity and Lt
is labor. If output is not
consumed or loaned out in any one period, then it spoils and cannot be carried over to
the following period (this just means that the economy cannot save internally, itís only way
to save would be to make international loans). This is a small open economy, so it can
borrow and lend freely at the constant-across-periods international interest rate r. The
households instantaneous utility is given by Ct=Lt and the household discounts the future
at rate , where: 2 (0; 1) is the households (constant) subjective discount factor (i.e.,
0 < < 1, where 2 means belongs and is the Greek letter beta); C is consumption;
L is labor. Moreover, the household owns the production function, so its thinking with
regards to its maximization problem is akin to that of a benevolent social planner. Now,
consider the following version of the households intertemporal utility maximization problem,
where A denotes the (endogenous) state variable ì(internationally traded) assets’ The
household chooses consumption, labor, and assets to maximize lifetime utility (hint: this
involves Ps=t+1
s=t
, for all purposes, as noted earlier, to some extent if it makes it
easier you can broadly think of this as t = 0 and t = 1; the explicit changes just
involve setting up certain things using s instead of our usual t, but at the end of
the day things should look entirely familiar: trust me!) such that
Cs + As+1  (1 + r) As + ZsLs
Let s denote the time-s Lagrange multiplier.
1. (Worth 15 points.) State the household is Lagrangian.
2. (Worth 35 points.) State the Worst order conditions for the household is (that is, the
economy is) utility maximization problem using s = t.
3. (Worth 50 points.) Is the following claim true, false, or uncertain? When the
economy is open, if =
1
1+r
, then the solution to the households period-t intertemporal
1
utility maximization problem implies that Ct+1 =
Zt+1
Zt
Ct
. (Note: again, if it is
easier to think about this, you can just imagine that t = 0, in which case
the question is asking whether it is true C1 =
Z1
Z0
C0:) Justify your answer with
thorough mathematical detail. (Huge hint: There are three ways through which Ct+1,
Ct, Zt+1, and Zt can meet in this problem. The Worst way is really straightforward and
involves combining two FOCs. The second will be revealed by going through our “usual
thing” in the small open economy case, which is equating the slope of an indifference
curve with the slope of the lifetime budget constraint. I’m not saying that equating the
slope is the solution, I’m saying that in going through these steps you’ll see the second
instance in which all of these variables meet. The last is a potential combination
between the Worst and second ways. Thetis it, you do those three things and they are
exhaustive to be able to answer the claim.)
2

 

 

 

 

Sample Solution

 

 

 

Tokyo Skytree

GuidesorSubmit my paper for examination

enlightening exposition sampleJapan is broadly known as a nation of marvels. Also its radiant complexities on the edge of advancement and conventionalism, this nation can flaunt unbelievably delightful nature, rich culture, and innovative advancement that has outpaced the remainder of the world for quite a long time. One of the indications of this advancement is the well known Tokyo Skytree: a colossal high rise manufactured right in the downtown area, which has changed the city’s appearance significantly.

The Tokyo Skytree has a place with the most unmistakable developments at any point raised by individuals. It is an interchanges and perception tower situated in the Sumida region. It would not be a distortion to state it very well may be seen at practically wherever in Tokyo, since it is so inconceivably high.

To be exact, the Tokyo Skytree is 2,080 feet high, which makes it Japan’s tallest structure, and the second most noteworthy structure on the planet, before the well known Burj Khalifa. Right now, organizations, eateries, and perception grounds are found, so anybody can appreciate the scene from the Skytree’s statures.

The pinnacle helps to remember an immense tripod in its base, and at the half of its tallness (1,050 feet) its three “legs” conjoin and structure a chamber, which makes prospects for all encompassing perspectives all over its edge. The pinnacle is painted in a shading that is authoritatively called Skytree White. It is said that this pale blue white shading depends on the purported Aijiro shading, which is customary for Japanese visual expressions. Additionally, the pinnacle is enlightened with LED lights, so the Tokyo Skytree’s hues change every day, from pale purple to sky blue.

Because of the utilization of present day innovations, Tokyo Skytree can likewise withstand even amazing seismic tremors, which happen in Japan rather regularly.

The Tokyo Skytree no ifs, ands or buts is a marvel of innovation and modern plan. It makes Tokyo, which has reliably been cutting edge, resemble a city from the far off future. Also, thinking about Japan’s consistent development and advancement, numerous other modern structures will be raised.

design article, e

 

 

 

This question has been answered.

Get Answer
WeCreativez WhatsApp Support
Our customer support team is here to answer your questions. Ask us anything!
👋 Hi, Welcome to Compliant Papers.