Simulation and Discussion

 

Competition Game: Price and quantity competition and CO2 environmental policies (quotas, taxes and emission permits)
Impact of environmental policies in a setting with quantity precommitment followed by price competition. Players repeatedly take price and quantity
decisions on four markets subject to different environmental policies for CO2 emissions: no policy benchmark, unit taxes, quotas or permits. Also available
as a multiplayer game (“5 IO Market Games” Section).
https://economics-games.com/game/slide/10000000007010
Market game with CO2 environmental policies
This game lets you apply many important microeconomics concepts. By adapting your debriefings, you can use it both as an introduction to microeconomics
or environmental economics or as a course illustration for more advanced students.
Sales Results
Rules as explained to players:
Timeline
You are responsible for managing a firm selling a good whose production emits CO2. You will play the same game against the same players on 4 completely
separate markets: Actions on one market do not have any direct impact on other markets. You can see these markets as parallel universes in which demand
and production costs are the same, but environmental policies are different (one market is a benchmark market, on the second there is a unit CO2 tax, on the
third you must respect a quota on emissions, and on the fourth you can buy or sell tradable emission permits. This will be detailed on the production page).
Note in particular, that goods produced on one market cannot be sold on other markets.
The timeline is separated into years. At beginning of the year, you have to choose how much to produce. Then, once every firm has decided how much to
produce, production takes place and you have to choose the price at which you will sell your goods.
For pedagogic reasons and to allow you to correct potential pricing mistakes, you will play the “sales part” twice (but this does not correspond to any realworld situation). We call these two sales sequences: “rounds” (for each round, the maximum quantity you can sell is equal to the total quantity you selected
at the production stage).
Demand on markets is proportional to the number of players and is the same as in the other market games from this site (but different from demand of
similar games found on lud.io (Links to an external site.)). In particular,
If every player charges a price equal to 50€, each player will sell about 694 goods.
If every player charges a price equal to 40€, each player will sell about 762 goods.
Average Individual Sales (if every firm chooses the same price)
Price 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 140
Demand 762 694 633 575 522 471 423 377 334 291 251
Note that goods are perishable: what is not sold at the end of a round is lost.
Finally, your shareholders only leave enough cash in your firm to let you produce a maximum of 1200 goods per round on each market (note that this does
not mean that producing 1200 goods is a good idea!). This constraint applies market by market.
Your goal is to maximize your company’s profit, not to beat your direct competitors, nor to sell the maximum number of goods (your final ranking will be
determined by comparing your profits with those of every other players, some of which may compete in different “universes”).
The game lasts three years.
Game details:
The game lasts three years, the cost structure is the same on all markets and there is a different environmental policy on each market Pricing
Technology on all markets
Each good produced will cost €15 and emit 0.5 tons of CO2, even if it is not sold. If it is sold, it will also cost an additional €4.
Unit production cost Unit distribution cost CO2 emissions (tons) per good produced
€15 €4 0.5
Environmental Policies
Market 1 is a benchmark market, there is no environmental policy.
On market 2, there is a CO2 emissions tax equal to €40 for each ton of emitted CO2 (that means each good produced costs an extra €20).
On market 3, there are (non-tradable) quotas. A firm cannot emit more than 300 tons of CO2 by round (or 600 tons by year). Consequently it can not produce
more than 600 goods by round
Market 4 is regulated with CO2 emissions permits. Each year, each firm receives 600 permits for free (that is, 300 permits for each round). With a permit, a
firm can emit one ton of CO2 at no cost. If a firm emits more CO2 than it has permits, it must buy permits at a price of €40 for each exceeding ton of CO2. If it
emits less CO2 than it has permits, it will be able to sell unused permits at a price of €40 each. (That means each firm can produce 600 goods by round with
no need to buy and no possibility to resell permits. If it want to produce more, it needs to buy extra permits, which costs €20 by additional good. If it produces
less, it can resell permits, which yields €20 for each good which is not produced.)
Note that for a €40 unit tax for each ton of CO2, producing 1000 goods costs €(15+0.5*40)*1000, i.e. €35000. If firms all decide to produce 1000 goods, they
will find themselves in the same situation as in one of the markets of the first competition game (Links to an external site.) of this site (Impact of fixed costs
and capacity constraints on price and profit, with differentiated goods)
Production
You can play this demo to get an idea of the game: , and find the same information inside this document: .
Choose the number of players and the number of different universes: If there are 30 players and you choose 3 universes, the students will be randomly
spread across 3 universes with 10 players: Players will be faced with the same 9 direct competitors on all 4 markets.
Having several universes ensures that players really have incentives to pay more attention to payoffs and less attention to their ranking inside their universe.
Indeed, a player who is the first in an extremely competitive universe might end up with a bad overall ranking.
Note A few trial and error cycles are necessary to be able to define a sound strategy, so, for this game, it might be a good idea to invite your students to first
run the monoplayer variant, as a monopoly (located at the top of the game creation page, 3rd in the monoplayer simulations list): Players will then be able to
use the back button to compare different decisions.
environmental-economics-games.pdf
Post your results and explain them (200 words min.). Also, post 2 substantive responses to your peers, at least 100 words each.

 

 

 

Sample Solution

understudies. Given the expected worth of such figures propelling scholastic achievement and hence impacting results like maintenance, wearing down, and graduation rates, research is justified as it might give understanding into non-mental techniques that could be of possible benefit to this populace (Lamm, 2000) . Part I: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY Introduction The country is encountering a basic lack of medical care suppliers, a deficiency that is supposed to increment in the following five years, similarly as the biggest populace in our country’s set of experiences arrives at the age when expanded clinical consideration is essential (Pike, 2002). Staffing of emergency clinics, centers, and nursing homes is more basic than any time in recent memory as the enormous quantities of ‘people born after WW2’s start to understand the requirement for more continuous clinical mediation and long haul care. Interest in turning into a medical caretaker has disappeared as of late, presumably because of the historical bac

This question has been answered.

Get Answer
WeCreativez WhatsApp Support
Our customer support team is here to answer your questions. Ask us anything!
👋 Hi, Welcome to Compliant Papers.